INTERNET EDITION

  第1340号 1997年02月21日(金)

グリーンスパン証言関連

 半年に一度のグリーンスパンFED議長のハンフリー・ホーキンス法に基づく議会証言は、前回話題になった同議長の講演(12月05日)より、遙かに株価の水準、および上昇ペースに強い警戒感を示す内容となりました。
 12月05日の講演では、「 irrational exuberance 」(根拠なき陶酔)という今や有名になった言葉を使いながらも、それが80年代後半の日本市場を指すのか、直接的に今のアメリカの株を指すのか曖昧だった。しかし、今回の議会証言では、
 「 As you know, last December I put the question this way: "...how do we know
when irrational exuberance has unduly escalated asset values, which
then become subject to unexpected and prolonged contractions ...?
 と述べて、議長の懸念が直接に今のニューヨーク株式市場に向けられていることを示した。同議長は、今の低い長期金利に企業の極めて強い収益見通しが加われば今の株価は正当化されうるとしながらも、過去2年間の株価の上昇ペースは明らかに懸念材料であるとしている。議長は歴史をしばしば引き合いに出して、「今までの株価理論はもう古い。○○の新しい理論を援用すれば、今の株価や今後の株価は正当化される」「株価新時代が始まった」たぐいの論法は
But, regrettably, history is strewn with visions of such "new eras" that, in the end, have proven to be a mirage. In short, history counsels caution.
 と述べて、行き過ぎた強気論の危険性を指摘、仮にこの株価が下げに転じたときは、今のバランスの良い米経済の成長がとぎれてしまう危険性を指摘した。同議長は「株価新時代説」が正当性を持ちうる可能性として
  1. 市場の効率性を高めていること
  2. 世界的に市場規模が拡大し、競争条件もグローバルなものになっていること
  3. 情報技術の伝搬

などを指摘しながらも
 「 Such caution seems especially warranted with regard to the sharp
rise in equity prices during the past two years. These gains have
obviously raised questions of sustainability
 と、過去2年間の株価の上昇ペースに警告を発している。これは同議長が、今のアメリカ経済の順調な拡大ペースをもっとも脅かす危険性があるものとして「株価」を意識していることを示している。しかし、同議長は「だからただちに利上げする」とは言っていない。あくまでも、株価の上昇がアメリカ経済に「imbalances」を生む危険性を示し、その危険があるときには「行動を辞さない」と述べたわけである。
――――――――――
 同議長のインフレに対する見方は、昨年末から変わっていない。

〈インフレについて〉

1.(景気好調の中でも)インフレ抑制に役立っていた要因

  労働者の職維持に対する不安感

   コンピューターなどの新技術の進展・普及

   グローバル・コンペティション

   国内の規制緩和

2.上記要因は「一時的」である危険性

  労働者は自信を深めている

  労働賃金も上昇気配

3.予防的(PREEMPTIVE)引き締めも


 というもの。しかし、グリーンスパンは「インフレ抑制に役立っていた要因」を「一時的なものである可能性」を指摘しながらも、実はかなり持続的なものと考えているのではないかと思われる。全体的なトーンとしても、インフレに対する懸念は高まっているとは言えない。
――――――――――
 マスコミは取り上げないかもしれないが、グリーンスパン議長も米経済にきわめて強気なことは注目される。彼のエンディングの言葉はおもしろい。
 「 Although a central banker's occupational
responsibility is to stay on the lookout for trouble, even I must
admit that our economic prospects in general are quite favorable.
The flexibility of our market system and the vibrancy of our private
sector remain examples for the whole world to emulate. The Federal
Reserve will endeavor to do its part by continuing to foster a
monetary framework under which our citizens can prosper to the
fullest possible extent.
斜線の部分などは、クリントンでも言わない。

 マーケットの反応は一部は行き過ぎ、一部は妥当なものである。株はダウで一時120ドル程度下げ、結局50ドル強の下げにとどまったが、これはグリーンスパン発言に対する素直な反応といえる。債券は、やや売られ過ぎである。「金融政策は効果がラグしがちだから、preemptiveな利上げをする可能性も」と言っているが、賃金や物価が持続的に上がり出す兆候は出ていない。債券は今後徐々に買い戻されるのでは。ドルは上昇したが、これはショートの買い戻したが主だと思われる。今後しばらくは、ニューヨークの株とドルが脆弱性を増す可能性がある。

《グリーンスパン証言のポイント》

1.米経済の現状と先行きには、upbeat

  CPI 伸び率=2.75−3.0%

   失業率=5.25−5.5%

   実質GDP伸び率=2.0−2.25%

2.インフレには監視姿勢継続

3.株価は、「要警戒」

〈インフレについて〉

1.インフレ抑制に役立っていた要因

  労働者の職維持に対する不安感

   コンピューターなどの新技術の進展・普及

   グローバル・コンペティション

   国内の規制緩和

2.上記要因は「一時的」である危険性

  労働者は自信を深めている

  労働賃金も上昇気配

3.予防的(PREEMPTIVE)引き締めも

〈株価について〉

1.注意が必要

  市場にみなぎるやや行き過ぎとも思える楽観論

  上げのスピード(継続性に疑問)

2.“NEW ERAS" MIGHT BE A MIRAGE

3.利上げオプション残すが、当面は様子見のスタンス


グリーンスパン証言の全文
Monetary Policy Testimony and Report to the Congress
Testimony of Alan Greenspan
Chairman, Federal Reserve Board
February 26, 1997

I appreciate the opportunity to appear before this Committee to
present the Federal Reserve's semiannual report on monetary policy.

The performance of the U.S. economy over the past year has been
quite favorable. Real GDP growth picked up to more than three
percent over the four quarters of 1996, as the economy progressed
through its sixth year of expansion. Employers added more than
two-and-a-half million workers to their payrolls in 1996, and the
unemployment rate fell further. Nominal wages and salaries have
increased faster than prices, meaning workers have gained ground in
real terms, reflecting the benefits of rising productivity. Outside
the food and energy sectors, increases in consumer prices actually
have continued to edge lower, with core CPI inflation only 2-1/2
percent over the past twelve months.

Low inflation last year was both a symptom and a cause of the good
economy. It was symptomatic of the balance and solidity of the
expansion and the evident absence of major strains on resources. At
the same time, continued low levels of inflation and inflation
expectations have been a key support for healthy economic
performance. They have helped to create a financial and economic
environment conducive to strong capital spending and longer-range
planning generally, and so to sustained economic expansion.
Consequently, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) believes it
is crucial to keep inflation contained in the near term and
ultimately to move toward price stability.

Looking ahead, the members of the FOMC expect inflation to remain
low and the economy to grow appreciably further. However, as I shall
be discussing, the unusually good inflation performance of recent
years seems to owe in large part to some temporary factors, of
uncertain longevity. Thus, the FOMC continues to see the
distribution of inflation risks skewed to the upside and must remain
especially alert to the possible emergence of imbalances in
financial and product markets that ultimately could endanger the
maintenance of the low-inflation environment. Sustainable economic
expansion for 1997 and beyond depends on it.

For some, the benign inflation outcome of 1996 might be considered
surprising, as resource utilization rates--particularly of
labor--were in the neighborhood of those that historically have been
associated with building inflation pressures. To be sure, an
acceleration in nominal labor compensation, especially its wage
component, became evident over the past year. But the rate of pay
increase still was markedly less than historical relationships with
labor market conditions would have predicted. Atypical restraint on
compensation increases has been evident for a few years now and
appears to be mainly the consequence of greater worker insecurity.
In 1991, at the bottom of the recession, a survey of workers at
large firms by International Survey Research Corporation indicated
that 25 percent feared being laid off. In 1996, despite the sharply
lower unemployment rate and the tighter labor market, the same
survey organization found that 46 percent were fearful of a job
layoff.

The reluctance of workers to leave their jobs to seek other
employment as the labor market tightened has provided further
evidence of such concern, as has the tendency toward longer labor
union contracts. For many decades, contracts rarely exceeded three
years. Today, one can point to five- and six-year
contracts--contracts that are commonly characterized by an emphasis
on job security and that involve only modest wage increases. The low
level of work stoppages of recent years also attests to concern
about job security.

Thus, the willingness of workers in recent years to trade off
smaller increases in wages for greater job security seems to be
reasonably well documented. The unanswered question is why this
insecurity persisted even as the labor market, by all objective
measures, tightened considerably. One possibility may lie in the
rapid evolution of technologies in use in the work place.
Technological change almost surely has been an important impetus
behind corporate restructuring and downsizing. Also, it contributes
to the concern of workers that their job skills may become
inadequate. No longer can one expect to obtain all of one's lifetime
job skills with a high-school or college diploma. Indeed, continuing
education is perceived to be increasingly necessary to retain a job.
The more pressing need to update job skills is doubtless also a
factor in the marked expansion of on- the-job training programs,
especially in technical areas, in many of the nation's corporations.

Certainly, other factors have contributed to the softness in
compensation growth in the past few years. The sharp deceleration in
health care costs, of course, is cited frequently. Another is the
heightened pressure on firms and their workers in industries that
compete internationally. Domestic deregulation has had similar
effects on the intensity of competitive forces in some industries.
In any event, although I do not doubt that all these factors are
relevant, I would be surprised if they were nearly as important as
job insecurity.

If heightened job insecurity is the most significant explanation of
the break with the past in recent years, then it is important to
recognize that, as I indicated in last February's Humphrey-Hawkins
testimony, suppressed wage cost growth as a consequence of job
insecurity can be carried only so far. At some point, the tradeoff
of subdued wage growth for job security has to come to an end. In
other words, the relatively modest wage gains we have experienced
are a temporary rather than a lasting phenomenon because there is a
limit to the value of additional job security people are willing to
acquire in exchange for lesser increases in living standards. Even
if real wages were to remain permanently on a lower upward track
than otherwise as a result of the greater sense of insecurity, the
rate of change of wages would revert at some point to a normal
relationship with inflation. The unknown is when this transition
period will end.

Indeed, some recent evidence suggests that the labor markets bear
especially careful watching for signs that the return to more normal
patterns may be in process. The Bureau of Labor Statistics reports
that people were somewhat more willing to quit their jobs to seek
other employment in January than previously. The possibility that
this reflects greater confidence by workers accords with a recent
further rise in the percent of households responding to a Conference
Board survey who perceive that job availability is plentiful. Of
course, the job market has continued to be quite good recently;
employment in January registered robust growth and initial claims
for unemployment insurance have been at a relatively low level of
late. Wages rose faster in 1996 than in 1995 by most measures,
perhaps also raising questions about whether the transitional period
of unusually slow wage gains may be drawing to a close.

To be sure, the pickup in wage gains has not shown through to
underlying price inflation. Increases in the core CPI, as well as in
several broader measures of prices, have stayed subdued or even
edged off further in recent months. As best we can judge, faster
productivity growth last year meant that rising compensation gains
did not cause labor costs per unit of output to increase any more
rapidly. Non-labor costs, which are roughly a quarter of total
consolidated costs of the nonfinancial corporate sector, were little
changed in 1996.

Owing in part to this subdued behavior of unit costs, profits and
rates of return on capital have risen to high levels. As a
consequence, businesses believe that, were they to raise prices to
boost profits further, competitors with already ample profit margins
would not follow suit; instead, they would use the occasion to
capture a greater market share. This interplay is doubtless a
significant factor in the evident loss of pricing power in American
business.

Intensifying global competition also may be further restraining
domestic firms' ability to hike prices as well as wages. Clearly,
the appreciation of the dollar on balance over the past eighteen
months or so, together with low inflation in many of our trading
partners, has resulted in a marked decline in non-oil import prices
that has helped to damp domestic inflation pressures. Yet it is
important to emphasize that these influences, too, would be holding
down inflation only temporarily; they represent a transition to a
lower price level than would otherwise prevail, not to a permanently
lower rate of inflation.

Against the background of all these considerations, the FOMC has
recognized the need to remain vigilant for signs of potentially
inflationary imbalances that might, if not corrected promptly,
undermine our economic expansion. The FOMC in fact has signaled a
state of heightened alert for possible policy tightening since last
July in its policy directives. But, we have also taken care not to
act prematurely. The FOMC refrained from changing policy last
summer, despite expectations of a near-term policy firming by many
financial market participants. In light of the developments I've
just discussed affecting wages and prices, we thought inflation
might well remain damped, and in any case was unlikely to pick up
very rapidly, in part because the economic expansion appeared likely
to slow to a more sustainable pace. In the event, inflation has
remained quiescent since then.

Given the lags with which monetary policy affects the economy,
however, we cannot rule out a situation in which a preemptive policy
tightening may become appropriate before any sign of actual higher
inflation becomes evident. If the FOMC were to implement such an
action, it would be judging that the risks to the economic expansion
of waiting longer had increased unduly and had begun to outweigh the
advantages of waiting for uncertainties to be reduced by the
accumulation of more information about economic trends. Indeed, the
hallmark of a successful policy to foster sustainable economic
growth is that inflation does not rise. I find it ironic that our
actions in 1994-95 were criticized by some because inflation did not
turn upward. That outcome, of course, was the intent of the
tightening, and I am satisfied that our actions then were both
necessary and effective, and helped to foster the continued economic
expansion.

To be sure, 1997 is not 1994. The real federal funds rate today is
significantly higher than it was three years ago. Then we had just
completed an extended period of monetary ease which addressed the
credit stringencies of the early 1990s, and with the abatement of
the credit crunch, the low real funds rate of early 1994 was clearly
incompatible with containing inflation and sustaining growth going
forward. In February 1997, in contrast, our concern is a matter of
relative risks rather than of expected outcomes. The real funds
rate, judging by core inflation, is only slightly below its early
1995 peak for this cycle and might be at a level that will promote
continued non- inflationary growth, especially considering the
recent rise in the exchange value of the dollar. Nonetheless, we
cannot be sure. And the risks of being wrong are clearly tilted to
the upside.

I wish it were possible to lay out in advance exactly what
conditions have to prevail to portend a buildup of inflation
pressures or inflationary psychology. However, the circumstances
that have been associated with increasing inflation in the past have
not followed a single pattern. The processes have differed from
cycle to cycle, and what may have been a useful leading indicator in
one instance has given off misleading signals in another.

I have already discussed the key role of labor market developments
in restraining inflation in the current cycle and our careful
monitoring of signs that the transition phase of trading off lower
real wages for greater job security might be coming to a close. As
always, with resource utilization rates high, we would need to watch
closely a situation in which demand was clearly unsustainable
because it was producing escalating pressures on resources, which
could destabilize the economy. And we would need to be watchful that
the progress we have made in keeping inflation expectations damped
was not eroding. In general, though, our analysis will need to
encompass all potentially relevant information, from financial
markets as well as the economy, especially when some signals, like
those in the labor market, have not been following their established
patterns.

The ongoing economic expansion to date has reinforced our conviction
about the importance of low inflation--and the public's confidence
in continued low inflation. The economic expansion almost surely
would not have lasted nearly so long had monetary policy supported
an unsustainable acceleration of spending that induced a buildup of
inflationary imbalances. The Federal Reserve must not acquiesce in
an upcreep in inflation, for acceding to higher inflation would
countenance an insidious weakening of our chances for sustaining
long-run economic growth. Inflation interferes with the efficient
allocation of resources by confusing price signals, undercutting a
focus on the longer run, and distorting incentives.

This year overall inflation is anticipated to stay restrained. The
central tendency of the forecasts made by the Board members and
Reserve Bank presidents has the increase in the total CPI slipping
back into a range of 2-3/4 to 3 percent over the four quarters of
the year. This slight falloff from last year's pace is expected to
owe in part to a slower rise in food prices as some of last year's
supply limitations ease. More importantly, world oil supplies are
projected by most analysts to increase relative to world oil demand,
and futures markets project a further decline in prices, at least in
the near term. The recent and prospective declines in crude oil
prices not only should affect retail gasoline and home heating oil
prices but also should relieve inflation pressures through lower
prices for other petroleum products, which are imbedded in the
economy's underlying cost structure. Nonetheless, the trend in
inflation rates in the core CPI and in broader price measures may be
somewhat less favorable than in recent years. A continued tight
labor market, whose influence on costs would be augmented by the
scheduled increase in the minimum wage later in the year and perhaps
by higher growth of benefits now that considerable health-care
savings already have been realized, could put upward pressure on
core inflation. Moreover, the effects of the sharp rise in the
dollar over the last eighteen months in pushing down import prices
are likely to ebb over coming quarters.

The unemployment rate, according to Board members and Bank
presidents, should stay around 5-1/4 to 5-1/2 percent through the
fourth quarter, consistent with their projections of measured real
GDP growth of 2 to 2-1/4 percent over the four quarters of the year.
Such a growth rate would represent some downshifting in output
expansion from that of last year. The projected moderation of growth
likely would reflect several influences: (1) declines in real
federal government purchases should be exerting a modest degree of
restraint on overall demand; (2) the lagged effects of the increase
in the exchange value of the dollar in recent months likely will
damp U.S. net exports somewhat this year; and (3) residential
construction is unlikely to repeat the gains of 1996. On the other
hand, we do not see evidence of widespread imbalances either in
business inventories or in stocks of equipment and consumer durables
that would lead to a substantial cutback in spending. And financial
conditions overall remain supportive; real interest rates are not
high by historical standards and credit is readily available from
intermediaries and in the market.

The usual uncertainties in the overall outlook are especially
focused on the behavior of consumers. Consumption should rise
roughly in line with the projected moderate expansion of disposable
income, but both upside and downside risks are present. According to
various surveys, sentiment is decidedly upbeat. Consumers have
enjoyed healthy gains in their real incomes along with the
extraordinary stock-market driven rise in their financial wealth
over the last couple of years. Indeed, econometric models suggest
that the more than $4 trillion rise in equity values since late 1994
should have had a larger positive influence on consumer spending
than seems to have actually occurred.

It is possible, however, that households have been reluctant to
spend much of their added wealth because they see a greater need to
keep it to support spending in retirement. Many households have
expressed heightened concern about their financial security in old
age, which reportedly has led to increased provision for retirement.
The results of a survey conducted annually by the Roper
Organization, which asks individuals about their confidence in the
Social Security system, shows that between 1992 and 1996 the percent
of respondents expressing little or no confidence in the system
jumped from about 45 percent to more than 60 percent.

Moreover, consumer debt burdens are near historical highs, while
credit card delinquencies and personal bankruptcies have risen
sharply over the past year. These circumstances may make both
borrowers and lenders a bit more cautious, damping spending. In
fact, we may be seeing both wealth and debt effects already at work
for different segments of the population, to an approximately
offsetting extent. Saving out of current income by households in the
upper income quintile, who own nearly three-fourths of all
non-pension equities held by households, evidently has declined in
recent years. At the same time, the use of credit for purchases
appears to have leveled off after a sharp runup from 1993 to 1996,
perhaps because some households are becoming debt constrained and,
as a result, are curtailing their spending.

The Federal Reserve will be weighing these influences as it
endeavors to help extend the current period of sustained growth.
Participants in financial markets seem to believe that in the
current benign environment the FOMC will succeed indefinitely. There
is no evidence, however, that the business cycle has been repealed.
Another recession will doubtless occur some day owing to
circumstances that could not be, or at least were not, perceived by
policymakers and financial market participants alike. History
demonstrates that participants in financial markets are susceptible
to waves of optimism, which can in turn foster a general process of
asset-price inflation that can feed through into markets for goods
and services. Excessive optimism sows the seeds of its own reversal
in the form of imbalances that tend to grow over time. When
unwarranted expectations ultimately are not realized, the unwinding
of these financial excesses can act to amplify a downturn in
economic activity, much as they can amplify the upswing. As you
know, last December I put the question this way: "...how do we know
when irrational exuberance has unduly escalated asset values, which
then become subject to unexpected and prolonged contractions ...?"

We have not been able, as yet, to provide a satisfying answer to
this question, but there are reasons in the current environment to
keep this question on the table. Clearly, when people are exposed to
long periods of relative economic tranquility, they seem inevitably
prone to complacency about the future. This is understandable. We
have had fifteen years of economic expansion interrupted by only one
recession--and that was six years ago. As the memory of such past
events fades, it naturally seems ever less sensible to keep up one's
guard against an adverse event in the future. Thus, it should come
as no surprise that, after such a long period of balanced expansion,
risk premiums for advancing funds to businesses in virtually all
financial markets have declined to near- record lows.

Is it possible that there is something fundamentally new about this
current period that would warrant such complacency? Yes, it is
possible. Markets may have become more efficient, competition is
more global, and information technology has doubtless enhanced the
stability of business operations. But, regrettably, history is
strewn with visions of such "new eras" that, in the end, have proven
to be a mirage. In short, history counsels caution.

Such caution seems especially warranted with regard to the sharp
rise in equity prices during the past two years. These gains have
obviously raised questions of sustainability. Analytically, current
stock-price valuations at prevailing long-term interest rates could
be justified by very strong earnings growth expectations. In fact,
the long-term earnings projections of financial analysts have been
marked up noticeably over the last year and seem to imply very high
earnings growth and continued rising profit margins, at a time when
such margins are already up appreciably from their depressed levels
of five years ago. It could be argued that, although margins are the
highest in a generation, they are still below those that prevailed
in the 1960s. Nonetheless, further increases in these margins would
evidently require continued restraint on costs: labor compensation
continuing to grow at its current pace and productivity growth
picking up. Neither, of course, can be ruled out. But we should keep
in mind that, at these relatively low long-term interest rates,
small changes in long-term earnings expectations could have outsized
impacts on equity prices.

Caution also seems warranted by the narrow yield spreads that
suggest perceptions of low risk, possibly unrealistically low risk.
Considerable optimism about the ability of businesses to sustain
this current healthy financial condition seems, as I indicated
earlier, to be influencing the setting of risk premiums, not just in
the stock market but throughout the financial system. This
optimistic attitude has become especially evident in quality spreads
on high- yield corporate bonds--what we used to call "junk bonds."
In addition, banks have continued to ease terms and standards on
business loans, and margins on many of these loans are now quite
thin. Many banks are pulling back a little from consumer credit card
lending as losses exceed expectations. Nonetheless, some bank and
nonbank lenders have been expanding aggressively into the home
equity loan market and so-called "subprime" auto lending, although
recent problems in the latter may already be introducing a sense of
caution.

Why should the central bank be concerned about the possibility that
financial markets may be overestimating returns or mispricing risk?
It is not that we have a firm view that equity prices are
necessarily excessive right now or risk spreads patently too low.
Our goal is to contribute as best we can to the highest possible
growth of income and wealth over time, and we would be pleased if
the favorable economic environment projected in markets actually
comes to pass. Rather, the FOMC has to be sensitive to indications
of even slowly building imbalances, whatever their source, that, by
fostering the emergence of inflation pressures, would ultimately
threaten healthy economic expansion.

Unfortunately, because the monetary aggregates were subject to an
episode of aberrant behavioral patterns in the early 1990s, they are
likely to be of only limited help in making this judgment. For three
decades starting in the early 1960s, the public's demand for the
broader monetary aggregates, especially M2, was reasonably
predictable. In the intermediate term, M2 velocity--nominal income
divided by the stock of M2--tended to vary directly with the
difference between money market yields and the return on M2
assets--that is, with its short-term opportunity cost. In the long
run, as adjustments in deposit rates caused the opportunity cost to
revert to an equilibrium, M2 velocity also tended to return to an
associated stable equilibrium level. For several years in the early
1990s, however, the velocities of M2 and M3 exhibited persisting
upward shifts that departed markedly from these historical patterns.

In the last two to three years, velocity patterns seem to have
returned to those historical relationships, after allowing for a
presumed permanent upward shift in the levels of velocity. Even so,
given the abnormal velocity behavior during the early 1990s, FOMC
members continue to see considerable uncertainty in the relationship
of broad money to opportunity costs and nominal income. Concern
about the possibility of aberrant behavior has made the FOMC
hesitant to upgrade the role of these measures in monetary policy.

Against this background, at its February meeting, the FOMC
reaffirmed the provisional ranges set last July for money and debt
growth this year: 1 to 5 percent for M2, 2 to 6 percent for M3, and
3 to 7 percent for the debt of domestic nonfinancial sectors. The M2
and M3 ranges again are designed to be consistent with the FOMC's
long-run goal of price stability: For, if the velocities of the
broader monetary aggregates were to continue behaving as they did
before 1990, then money growth around the middle portions of the
ranges would be consistent with noninflationary, sustainable
economic expansion. But, even with such velocity behavior this year,
when inflation is expected to still be higher than is consistent
with our long-run objective of reasonable price stability, the
broader aggregates could well grow around the upper bounds of these
ranges. The debt aggregate probably will expand around the middle of
its range this year.

I will conclude on the same upbeat note about the U.S. economy with
which I began. Although a central banker's occupational
responsibility is to stay on the lookout for trouble, even I must
admit that our economic prospects in general are quite favorable.
The flexibility of our market system and the vibrancy of our private
sector remain examples for the whole world to emulate. The Federal
Reserve will endeavor to do its part by continuing to foster a
monetary framework under which our citizens can prosper to the
fullest possible extent.

dollar declines .............not by intervention

 ドルは今週、2月8日のG7以来初めて目に見える形で大きく下落しました。特に木曜日のニューヨーク市場に入ってからの下げはきつかった。ドイツの今年1月のIFO景況指数(製造業、建設、卸売り部門対象)が、12月の90.0(当初発表は91.0)から、93.3に大幅に上昇(エコノミストの予想平均は91.1だった)したとの報道などが「ドル安の材料」とされているものの、これとは別に

  1. ドイツ当局者の「一層のドル高」に対する警告などが続く中で、一段のドル高に対する介入警戒感が引き続き強いこと
  2. 米貿易収支赤字の拡大傾向、アメリカの景気の先行きに対するさめた見方の台頭など、アメリカ経済および当局のドル高許容度に関する疑念の台頭
  3. アメリカの資産市場が、株がダウで7000ドルに乗せた後、足踏み状態を続けていることでドルを買い持ちにすることへの安心感に対する疑念

 などが市場ではみられ、これらが重なってドルの大幅な下げを誘発したものと思われる。最初の当局の介入に対する懸念は、G7合意が「妥協の産物」「玉虫色の合意」「フランスは反対していた」など様々な疑念や評価が入り乱れる中でも、徐々に高まっていたもの。中央銀行の中で一番介入政策に消極的で、実体経済面でも「介入の必要性」が一番低いと見られているドイツ連銀の当局者は、今週だけでティートマイヤー・ドイツ連銀総裁初め数人が何回にも渡って「より一段の持続的なドル高」に対する反対の意向を表明した。このことが、市場のドル強気論を弱めたと言える。

 また、今週の為替関連の記事の中には、週央のウォール・ストリート・ジャーナルの「最後に笑うのは、中央銀行かもしれない」といった記事のように、市場の疑念にもかかわらず介入の可能性を強く示唆する見方もあった。また、市場では「G7では介入のレベルまで決まっていた」といったような未確認情報も流れていた。125円を手前で何回もずり落ちるドルに対して、いったん売りが出てもおかしくはない時期だったとも言える。そういう意味では、G7後の為替相場は対マルクではやや上昇しているものの、いままでのところは当局の「取り組み勝ち」となっている。

but with fear and its own gravity

 しかし、介入懸念だけではなく、ドルはそれ自身が最近にない「重力」を感じ始めていたことも確かである。G7直後の「にもかかわらずドルは上昇する」との一般的な見通しがアメリカ経済のファンダメンタルズに支えられていれば、ドルは多少の介入懸念にも関わらず、上昇していてもおかしくなかった。

 その「重力」とは、一つはアメリカの資産市場、特に株式市場に対する高値警戒感。ダウで7000ドルに乗った直後は、「まだ行く」との見方が強かったものの、やはりその後は警戒感との綱引きで、さらに買い上げるという雰囲気ではない。木曜日のニューヨークの株式市場は、そうしたもたれ感もあり、ダウ平均は 92.75ドル下げて6927.38ドルと、7000ドルを割った。The Standard & Poor's 500種指数は、9.72ドル安の802.77ドル、 New York Stock Exchange Composite Indexは、4.48ドル安の421.09ドル。

 今週は株に関する記事がいっぱいアメリカのマスコミにもあって、7000ドルに乗った直後の記事は、どちらかというとその持続性や、上昇のスピードに対する懸念を表明するものが多かった。ある記事は、 

 「ウォール・ストリートはますます1980年代の東京に似てきた。東京の株はピーク時に、日本のGDPの140%まで上がったが、今のニューヨークは同じ基準で133%になっている」(ニューヨーク・タイムズ)

 とまで書いていた。当時の日本と今のアメリカを単純に比べるのはむろん問題があります。当時(1980年代の後半)私は、日本経済を「圧力鍋経済」と呼んでいた。円高で資金は外に出ていかない。国内は超低金利。規制の緩和も進んでいない。まあ、いってみれば閉ざされた国での資産価格の大幅な上昇。ですから、土地から株からゴルフ会員権からすべて上がった。

 しかし、今のアメリカは十分に市場を開放した上での株価上昇です。確かに速い。しかし、ニューヨークに上場されている株が、「アメリカ株」だと思うのも間違っていると思います。あれは、実質的に「多国籍企業」の株の集合体です。ですから、アメリカ経済の命運とだけ結びつけるのには無理がある。市場を引っ張っているのは、世界中の消費者を相手としているハイテク企業です。しかし、株価の上昇ペースそのものには、懸念が残っている。今日あたりに講演を予定しているグリーンスパンFED議長の発言などが注目される。

 為替に話を戻すと、むろん今朝のウォール・ストリート・ジャーナルの為替市況記事のように、「ドルはすぐ底を見つけて、反発するものと予想されている」という見方も強い。しかし、米12月の月間、それに昨年一年間の貿易収支の大幅赤字や、物価指数が出る度にその可能性が後退する利上げ観測などが、ドルの頭を重くしている。それに、介入懸念。

 日本サイドから見ると、4−6月について予約がほぼゼロとなっている輸出業者の動きが新たなポイントでしょう。ドル高見通しが強かっただけに、輸出業者の予約率は低い。また、日本株が上昇し、債券利回りが一時的にも上昇する中で、資本の流れにも気をつけたい。

many many fire drills

 ケ小平氏死去は、「もう避難訓練を何十回となくやった」(当社香港支店)ということもあって、市場では大きな材料にされていない。香港の株も昨日は堅調推移。これまで比較的高かった香港ドルの短期金利も、むしろ不安感一掃から低下した。

 今朝の日経の春秋に書いてありますが、ケ小平さんは、香港の中国返還を一目見たかったのではないでしょうか。台湾問題以上に、中国にとっては香港は「誇れない歴史」を引きずったものでしたから。でも、92歳のご高齢でしたから、病名(パーキンソン氏病)はついていても天寿を全うされたというのが当たっていると思います。

 ――――――――――
「避難訓練」という観点では、日本で何回も取りざたされる金融不安とそれへの対処が実際に起きたときに、為替、株、債券に何が起きるかを十分に考えておく必要があるでしょう。昨日の「総合土地対策」の報で、株価は大きく上げましたが、危機が顕在化してくればくるほど、それに対する民間、政府の対策が出てくる。たとえば、住専の時におおもめに揉めた公的資金が、今度は危機対策で実際に投入されることが決まった時に、為替、株、債券に何が起きるかです。

 昨日の株の動きは、まあ言ってみればそれに近い動きと言えるかもしれない。むろん、実際にどのような対策が出るかが一番重要で、それは今から正確には予測できないのですが、シミュレーションをしておく必要はある。マーケットは常に「先取り」が原則ですから、一番危機的に見えるときに、「次の動き」を織り込もうとする。

have a nice weekend

 寒い日と暖かい日が交互にくる感じがしますね。でも、日差しは着実に強くなっている。風邪はまだ猛威をふるっているようです。お気をつけて。

 今週は、月曜日に名古屋にお伺いしました。風が強かったですね。大勢の方にいらっしていただいて、質問も多かったのが皆さんのご興味が深かったことを示しています。私のe-mail番号を出席者に残しておきましたら、3人のお客様からあとでメールをいただきました。こういう形が今後も増えていくんでしょうね。この日は、ちょうど名古屋の法人営業部長に赴任した服部君が、朝4時起きで東京から名古屋に赴任した日で、彼は眠そうでしたな。ゴルフは全方位powerful hitter、麻雀は誰かのリーチに挑むときは、まずそいつの顔を睨んでからパイを曲げるという癖を持つ。パワフルな男です。名古屋とその周辺の皆様には、よろしく。

 ――――――――――
 今週多少賢くなったと思うのは、マイクロソフトのプレゼンテーション・ソフトである「Power point」を覚えたことでしょうか。このソフトは、今までも講演の時に使ったことはありますが、市場金融部の町田君や森山君に作ってもらっていた。しかし、情けない。自分のプレゼンテーションなのに。そこで、一念発起。でも、始めたら早かった。「筆まめ君」マスター程度のソフトですな、あれは。むろん使いこなすには、まだいろいろな隠し技があるのでしょうが。使うメリットは、「便利・綺麗」ということでしょうか。ワープロ程度の知識で2〜3時間でマスターできます。

 まだ寒い。週末はゆっくりとお休みください。

                 

                    
           <ycaster@gol.com>